Rights versus Underwritten Offerings: An Asymmetric Information Approach
Pages: 1-18 | Published: 3/1986 | DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1986.tb04488.x | Cited by: 60
ROBERT HEINKEL, EDUARDO S. SCHWARTZ
Asymmetric Information and Risky Debt Maturity Choice
Pages: 19-37 | Published: 3/1986 | DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1986.tb04489.x | Cited by: 631
MARK J. FLANNERY
When capital market investors and firm insiders possess the same information about a company's prospects, its liabilities will be priced in a way that makes the firm indifferent to the composition of its financial liabilities (at least under certain, well‐known circumstances). However, if firm insiders are systematically better informed than outside investors, they will choose to issue those types of securities that the market appears to overvalue most. Knowing this, rational investors will try to infer the insiders' information from the firm's financial structure. This paper evaluates the extent to which a firm's choice of risky debt maturity can signal insiders' information about firm quality. If financial market transactions are costless, a firm's financial structure cannot provide a valid signal. With positive transaction costs, however, high‐quality firms can sometimes effectively signal their true quality to the market. The existence of a signalling equilibrium is shown to depend on the (exogenous) distribution of firms' quality and the magnitude of underwriting costs for corporate debt.
Informational Efficiency and Information Subsets
Pages: 39-52 | Published: 3/1986 | DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1986.tb04490.x | Cited by: 15
MARK LATHAM
This paper proposes a new definition of the Efficient Markets Hypothesis with respect to information, which is more formal and precise than those of Rubinstein [13], Fama [4], Jensen [6], and Beaver [1], and which fits well as a framework for interpreting the many tests of the Efficient Markets Hypothesis in the literature. Security markets are here considered “efficient with respect to information set ϕ” if and only if revealing ϕ to all agents would change neither equilibrium prices nor portfolios. In addition to other desirable features, this definition has the “subset property”: efficiency with respect to ϕ implies efficiency with respect to any subset of ϕ.
The Effects of Different Taxes on Risky and Risk‐free Investment and on the Cost of Capital
Pages: 53-66 | Published: 3/1986 | DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1986.tb04491.x | Cited by: 2
YU ZHU, IRWIN FRIEND
This paper analyzes the major factors which determine the effects of taxation on the value of risky assets and on the cost of capital, and shows how the magnitudes and even the signs of these effects depend on the values assumed for a few key parameters in the model. Using plausible values for these parameters, it is shown that the results obtained are frequently counter‐intuitive.
A Utility‐Based Model of Common Stock Price Movements
Pages: 67-92 | Published: 3/1986 | DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1986.tb04492.x | Cited by: 12
ROBERT H. LITZENBERGER, EHUD I. RONN
This paper develops and tests a nonlinear utility‐based econometric model of the temporal behavior of aggregate stock price movements based on a constant relative risk aversion utility function and an observable information set consisting of aggregate consumption, aggregate dividends, and past stock prices. The stochastic process derived from time‐series analyses of consumption and dividends measured over annual intervals is used to derive and empirically test a closed‐form solution for stock‐price movements. The endogenization of discount rate changes in the utility‐based model is shown to be more consistent with aggregate stock price movements over a twenty‐year holdout period than constant discount rate models. The model is also used to estimate the representative investor's relative risk aversion. The estimate of 4.22 is consistent with that used by Grossman and Shiller in their perfect foresight model and is significantly higher than the relative risk aversion of 1.0 implied by logarithmic utility.
Stock Price Movements in Response to Stock Issues under Asymmetric Information
Pages: 93-105 | Published: 3/1986 | DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1986.tb04493.x | Cited by: 124
WILLIAM S. KRASKER
This paper characterizes the function relating the number of new shares issued by a firm to the resulting change in the firm's stock price, when insiders are asymmetrically informed. We show that, in equilibrium, the stock price will be a decreasing function of the issue size; moreover, the rate of decrease can be so rapid to cause “equity rationing.” We also show that there will be underinvestment relative to the symmetric information case.
Earnings Announcements, Stock Price Adjustment, and the Existence of Option Markets
Pages: 107-125 | Published: 3/1986 | DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1986.tb04494.x | Cited by: 126
ROBERT JENNINGS, LAURA STARKS
This paper employs a new approach to study the effects of option trading on the behavior of underlying stock prices. Extant research compares distributional properties of the stock price at two points in time divided by an event in the option market that might affect price behavior. As an alternative, we examine the stock price adjustment to the release of quarterly earnings using samples of firms with and without listed options. We find the two samples exhibit different adjustment processes, with the nonoption firms requiring substantially more time to adjust.
Valuation of American Futures Options: Theory and Empirical Tests
Pages: 127-150 | Published: 3/1986 | DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1986.tb04495.x | Cited by: 94
ROBERT E. WHALEY
This paper reviews the theory of futures option pricing and tests the valuation principles on transaction prices from the S&P 500 equity futures option market. The American futures option valuation equations are shown to generate mispricing errors which are systematically related to the degree the option is in‐the‐money and to the option's time to expiration. The models are also shown to generate abnormal risk‐adjusted rates of return after transaction costs. The joint hypothesis that the American futures option pricing models are correctly specified and that the S&P 500 futures option market is efficient is refuted, at least for the sample period January 28, 1983 through December 30, 1983.
Efficiency Tests of the Foreign Currency Options Market
Pages: 151-162 | Published: 3/1986 | DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1986.tb04496.x | Cited by: 33
JAMES N. BODURTHA, GEORGES R. COURTADON
Beating the Foreign Exchange Market
Pages: 163-182 | Published: 3/1986 | DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1986.tb04497.x | Cited by: 199
RICHARD J. SWEENEY
Filter rule profits found in foreign exchange markets in the early days of the current managed float persist in later periods, as shown by statistical tests developed and implemented here. The test is consistent with, but independent of, a wide variety of asset pricing models. The profits found cannot be explained by risk if risk premia are constant over time. Inclusion of the home‐foreign interest rate differential in computing profits has little effect on the comparison of filter returns to those of buy‐and‐hold.
A Defense of Traditional Hypotheses about the Term Structure of Interest Rates
Pages: 183-193 | Published: 3/1986 | DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1986.tb04498.x | Cited by: 85
JOHN Y. CAMPBELL
Expectations theories of asset returns may be interpreted either as stating that risk premia are zero or that they are constant through time. Under the former interpretation, different versions of the expectations theory of the term structure are inconsistent with one another, but I show that this does not necessarily carry over to the constant risk premium interpretation of the theory. I present a general equilibrium example in which different types of risk premium are constant through time and dependent only on maturity. Furthermore, I argue that differences among expectations theories are second‐order effects of bond yield variability. I develop an approximate linearized framework for analysis of the term structure in which these differences disappear, and I test its accuracy in practice using data from the CRSP government bond tapes.
Valuation and Optimal Exercise of the Wild Card Option in the Treasury Bond Futures Market
Pages: 195-207 | Published: 3/1986 | DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1986.tb04499.x | Cited by: 30
ALEX KANE, ALAN J. MARCUS
The Chicago Board of Trade Treasury Bond Futures Contract allows the short position several delivery options as to when and with which bond the contract will be settled. The timing option allows the short position to choose any business day in the delivery month to make delivery. In addition, the contract settlement price is locked in at 2:00 p.m. when the futures market closes, despite the facts that the short position need not declare an intent to settle the contract until 8:00 p.m. and that trading in Treasury bonds can occur all day in dealer markets. If bond prices change significantly between 2:00 and 8:00 p.m., the short has the option of settling the contract at a favorable 2:00 p.m. price. This phenomenon, which recurs on every trading day of the delivery month, creates a sequence of 6‐hour put options for the short position which has been dubbed the “wild card option.” This paper presents a valuation model for the wild card option and computes estimates of the value of that option, as well as rules for its optimal exercise.
Asset Pricing and Expected Inflation
Pages: 209-223 | Published: 3/1986 | DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1986.tb04500.x | Cited by: 96
RENÉ M. STULZ
This paper provides an equilibrium model in which expected real returns on common stocks are negatively related to expected inflation and money growth. It is shown that the fall in real wealth associated with an increase in expected inflation decreases the real rate of interest and the expected real rate of return of the market portfolio. The expected real rate of return of the market portfolio falls less, for a given increase in expected inflation, when the increase in expected inflation is caused by an increase in money growth rather than by a worsening of the investment opportunity set. The model has empirical implications for the effect of a change in expected inflation on the cross‐sectional distribution of asset returns and can help to understand why assets whose return covaries positively with expected inflation may have lower expected returns. The model also agrees with explanations advanced by Fama [5] and Geske and Roll [10] for the negative relation between stock returns and inflation.
Excess Asset Reversions and Shareholder Wealth
Pages: 225-241 | Published: 3/1986 | DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1986.tb04501.x | Cited by: 23
MICHAEL J. ALDERSON, K. C. CHEN
The ownership of pension assets in a defined benefit pension plan is an unresolved issue in corporate finance. The issue is important because it defines the appropriate investment policy for a pension fund. In this paper, we summarize the ownership debate in the form of two mutually exclusive theories. We then focus on a recently popular event in pension finance, excess asset reversions. Our paper demonstrates the valuation effects associated with this event in a stochastic dominance framework. Under certain conditions, a reversion constitutes an expropriation of wealth from the participants and beneficiaries of the plan to the firm. Using data provided by the Pension Benefit Guaranty Corporation and the Center for Research in Security Prices tape, we examine the returns to the shareholders of 58 companies which conducted excess asset reversions between 1980 and 1984. Our results show that large abnormal returns accrued to these shareholders around the time of the reversion. These findings have implications both for the appropriate investment policy of pension funds and for public policy with respect to plan terminations.
LaPlace Transforms as Present Value Rules: A Note
Pages: 243-247 | Published: 3/1986 | DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1986.tb04502.x | Cited by: 17
STEPHEN A. BUSER
The present value equation in finance is shown to be equivalent to the Laplace transformation in mathematics. Based on this observation, the list of known analytic solutions for the present value problem is increased from a handful to more than one hundred. General properties of the Laplace transform are examined as well in light of the newly discovered significance for finance.
Pages: 249-253 | Published: 3/1986 | DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1986.tb04503.x | Cited by: 4
ANIL K. MAKHIJA, HOWARD E. THOMPSON
The Effect of Three Mile Island on Utility Bond Risk Premia: A Note
Pages: 255-261 | Published: 3/1986 | DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1986.tb04504.x | Cited by: 21
W. BRIAN BARRETT, ANDREA J. HEUSON, ROBERT W. KOLB
A Note on the Welfare Consequences of New Option Markets
Pages: 263-267 | Published: 3/1986 | DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1986.tb04505.x | Cited by: 1
BARRY SCHACHTER
Testing Portfolio Efficiency when the Zero‐Beta Rate is Unknown: A Note
Pages: 269-276 | Published: 3/1986 | DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1986.tb04506.x | Cited by: 32
JAY SHANKEN
A lower bound on the distribution function of the likelihood ratio test of portfolio efficiency is derived. An empirical application demonstrates that the bound may sometimes be used to infer rejection of the null hypothesis without appeal to asymptotic statistical approximations. A procedure for incorporating partial information about the zero‐beta intercept, in the multivariate framework, is also developed and applied.
Adjusting for Beta Bias: An Assessment of Alternate Techniques: A Note
Pages: 277-286 | Published: 3/1986 | DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1986.tb04507.x | Cited by: 41
THOMAS H. McINISH, ROBERT A. WOOD
This paper tests the effectiveness of techniques proposed by: Scholes‐Williams; Dimson; Fowler, Rorke, and Jog; and Cohen, Hawawini, Maier, Schwartz, and Whitcomb to control for bias in beta estimates from thin trading and price adjustment delays. Each technique produces beta estimates that reduce the amount of this bias, but the amount of reduction in the best case is only 29%.
Pages: 287-291 | Published: 3/1986 | DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1986.tb04508.x | Cited by: 0
Book reviewed in this article:
Pages: 292-293 | Published: 3/1986 | DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1986.tb04509.x | Cited by: 0