Pages: 1-40 | Published: 12/2001 | DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2001.tb00910.x | Cited by: 0
Pages: 2019-2065 | Published: 12/2001 | DOI: 10.1111/0022-1082.00398 | Cited by: 594
Vojislav Maksimovic, Gordon Phillips
We analyze the market for corporate assets. There is an active market for corporate assets, with close to seven percent of plants changing ownership annually through mergers, acquisitions, and asset sales in peak expansion years. The probability of asset sales and whole‐firm transactions is related to firm organization and ex ante efficiency of buyers and sellers. The timing of sales and the pattern of efficiency gains suggests that the transactions that occur, especially through asset sales of plants and divisions, tend to improve the allocation of resources and are consistent with a simple neoclassical model of profit maximizing by firms.
The Relative Valuation of Caps and Swaptions: Theory and Empirical Evidence
Pages: 2067-2109 | Published: 12/2001 | DOI: 10.1111/0022-1082.00399 | Cited by: 119
Francis A. Longstaff, Pedro Santa‐Clara, Eduardo S. Schwartz
Although traded as distinct products, caps and swaptions are linked by no‐arbitrage relations through the correlation structure of interest rates. Using a string market model, we solve for the correlation matrix implied by swaptions and examine the relative valuation of caps and swaptions. We find that swaption prices are generated by four factors and that implied correlations are lower than historical correlations. Long‐dated swaptions appear mispriced and there were major pricing distortions during the 1998 hedge‐fund crisis. Cap prices periodically deviate significantly from the no‐arbitrage values implied by the swaptions market.
Dividend Changes and Future Profitability
Pages: 2111-2133 | Published: 12/2001 | DOI: 10.1111/0022-1082.00400 | Cited by: 334
Doron Nissim, Amir Ziv
We investigate the relation between dividend changes and future profitability, measured in terms of either future earnings or future abnormal earnings. Supporting “the information content of dividends hypothesis,” we find that dividend changes provide information about the level of profitability in subsequent years, incremental to market and accounting data. We also document that dividend changes are positively related to earnings changes in each of the two years after the dividend change.
Characteristics of Risk and Return in Risk Arbitrage
Pages: 2135-2175 | Published: 12/2001 | DOI: 10.1111/0022-1082.00401 | Cited by: 543
Mark Mitchell, Todd Pulvino
This paper analyzes 4,750 mergers from 1963 to 1998 to characterize the risk and return in risk arbitrage. Results indicate that risk arbitrage returns are positively correlated with market returns in severely depreciating markets but uncorrelated with market returns in flat and appreciating markets. This suggests that returns to risk arbitrage are similar to those obtained from selling uncovered index put options. Using a contingent claims analysis that controls for the nonlinear relationship with market returns, and after controlling for transaction costs, we find that risk arbitrage generates excess returns of four percent per year.
The Determinants of Credit Spread Changes
Pages: 2177-2207 | Published: 12/2001 | DOI: 10.1111/0022-1082.00402 | Cited by: 1454
Pierre Collin-Dufresn, Robert S. Goldstein, J. Spencer Martin
Using dealer's quotes and transactions prices on straight industrial bonds, we investigate the determinants of credit spread changes. Variables that should in theory determine credit spread changes have rather limited explanatory power. Further, the residuals from this regression are highly cross‐correlated, and principal components analysis implies they are mostly driven by a single common factor. Although we consider several macroeconomic and financial variables as candidate proxies, we cannot explain this common systematic component. Our results suggest that monthly credit spread changes are principally driven by local supply/demand shocks that are independent of both credit‐risk factors and standard proxies for liquidity.
On the Perils of Financial Intermediaries Setting Security Prices: The Mutual Fund Wild Card Option
Pages: 2209-2236 | Published: 12/2001 | DOI: 10.1111/0022-1082.00403 | Cited by: 96
John M. R. Chalmers, Roger M. Edelen, Gregory B. Kadlec
Economic distortions can arise when financial claims trade at prices set by an intermediary rather than direct negotiation between principals. We demonstrate the problem in a specific context, the exchange of open‐end mutual fund shares. Mutual funds typically set fund share price (NAV) using an algorithm that fails to account for nonsynchronous trading in the fund's underlying securities. This results in predictable changes in NAV, which lead to exploitable trading opportunities. A modification to the pricing algorithm that corrects for nonsynchronous trading eliminates much of the predictability. However, there are many other potential sources of distortion when intermediaries set prices.
A Theory of the Syndicate: Form Follows Function
Pages: 2237-2264 | Published: 12/2001 | DOI: 10.1111/0022-1082.00404 | Cited by: 138
Pegaret Pichler, William Wilhelm
We relate the organizational form of investment banking syndicates to moral hazard in team production. Although syndicates are dissolved upon deal completion, membership stability across deals represents a barrier to entry that enables the capture of quasirents. This improves incentives for individual bankers to cultivate investor relationships that translate into greater expected proceeds. Reputational concerns of lead bankers amplify the effect. We derive conditions under which restricted entry and designation of a lead banker strictly Pareto dominate, in which case it is also strictly Pareto dominant for the syndicate's fee to be greater than members' cost of participation.
Internal Monitoring Mechanisms and CEO Turnover: A Long‐Term Perspective
Pages: 2265-2297 | Published: 12/2001 | DOI: 10.1111/0022-1082.00405 | Cited by: 734
Mark R. Huson, Robert Parrino, Laura T. Starks
We report evidence on chief executive officer (CEO) turnover during the 1971 to 1994 period. We find that the nature of CEO turnover activity has changed over time. The frequencies of forced CEO turnover and outside succession both increased. However, the relation between the likelihood of forced CEO turnover and firm performance did not change significantly from the beginning to the end of the period we examine, despite substantial changes in internal governance mechanisms. The evidence also indicates that changes in the intensity of the takeover market are not associated with changes in the sensitivity of CEO turnover to firm performance.
Executive Compensation and Corporate Acquisition Decisions
Pages: 2299-2336 | Published: 12/2001 | DOI: 10.1111/0022-1082.00406 | Cited by: 388
Sudip Datta, Mai Iskandar‐Datta, Kartik Raman
By examining how executive compensation structure determines corporate acquisition decisions, we document a strong positive relation between acquiring managers' equity‐based compensation (EBC) and stock price performance around and following acquisition announcements. This relation is highly robust when we control for acquisition mode (mergers), means of payment, managerial ownership, and previous option grants. Compared to low EBC managers, high EBC managers pay lower acquisition premiums, acquire targets with higher growth opportunities, and make acquisitions engendering larger increases in firm risk. EBC significantly explains postacquisition stock price performance even after controlling for acquisition mode, means of payment, and “glamour” versus “value” acquirers.
Bookbuilding and Strategic Allocation
Pages: 2337-2369 | Published: 12/2001 | DOI: 10.1111/0022-1082.00407 | Cited by: 301
Francesca Cornelli, David Goldreich
In the bookbuilding procedure, an investment banker solicits bids for shares from institutional investors prior to pricing an equity issue. The banker then prices the issue and allocates shares at his discretion to the investors. We examine the books for 39 international equity issues. We find that the investment banker awards more shares to bidders who provide information in their bids. Regular investors receive favorable allocations, especially when the issue is heavily oversubscribed. The investment banker also favors revised bids and domestic investors.
Pages: 2371-2388 | Published: 12/2001 | DOI: 10.1111/0022-1082.00408 | Cited by: 384
Michael J. Cooper, Orlin Dimitrov, P. Raghavendra Rau
We document a striking positive stock price reaction to the announcement of corporate name changes to Internet‐related dotcom names. This “dotcom” effect produces cumulative abnormal returns on the order of 74 percent for the 10 days surrounding the announcement day. The effect does not appear to be transitory; there is no evidence of a postannouncement negative drift. The announcement day effect is also similar across all firms, regardless of the firm's level of involvement with the Internet. A mere association with the Internet seems enough to provide a firm with a large and permanent value increase.
Feedback from Stock Prices to Cash Flows
Pages: 2389-2413 | Published: 12/2001 | DOI: 10.1111/0022-1082.00409 | Cited by: 195
Avanidhar Subrahmanyam, Sheridan Titman
Feedback from financial market prices to cash flows arises when a firm's nonfinancial stakeholders, for example, its customers, employees, and suppliers, make decisions that are contingent on the information revealed by the price. Complementarities across stakeholders result in cascades, wherein relatively small stock price moves trigger substantial changes in asset values. This paper analyzes the relation between such feedback effects and parameters such as the information cost, the volatility of existing projects, the risk aversion of liquidity suppliers, and the precision of managerial information.
Pages: 2415-2430 | Published: 12/2001 | DOI: 10.1111/0022-1082.00410 | Cited by: 278
Edwin J. Elton, Martin J. Gruber, Christopher R. Blake
This paper examines problems in the CRSP Survivor Bias Free U.S. Mutual Fund Database (CRSP, 1998) and compares returns contained in it to those in Morningstar. The CRSP database has an omission bias that has the same effects as survivorship bias. Although all mutual funds are listed in CRSP, return data is missing for many and the characteristics of these funds differ from the populations. The CRSP return data is biased upward and merger months are inaccurately recorded about half the time. Differences in returns in Morningstar and CRSP are a problem for older data and small funds.
The Stock Market Valuation of Research and Development Expenditures
Pages: 2431-2456 | Published: 12/2001 | DOI: 10.1111/0022-1082.00411 | Cited by: 1216
Louis K. C. Chan, Josef Lakonishok, Theodore Sougiannis
We examine whether stock prices fully value firms' intangible assets, specifically research and development (R&D). Under current U.S. accounting standards, financial statements do not report intangible assets and R&D spending is expensed. Nonetheless, the average historical stock returns of firms doing R&D matches the returns of firms without R&D. However, the market is apparently too pessimistic about beaten‐down R&D‐intensive technology stocks' prospects. Companies with high R&D to equity market value (which tend to have poor past returns) earn large excess returns. A similar relation exists between advertising and stock returns. R&D intensity is positively associated with return volatility.
Pages: 2465-2472 | Published: 12/2001 | DOI: 10.1111/0022-1082.00413 | Cited by: 0