Pages: 2471-2535 | Published: 11/2018 | DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12727 | Cited by: 362
ITZHAK BEN‐DAVID, FRANCESCO FRANZONI, RABIH MOUSSAWI
Due to their low trading costs, exchange‐traded funds (ETFs) are a potential catalyst for short‐horizon liquidity traders. The liquidity shocks can propagate to the underlying securities through the arbitrage channel, and ETFs may increase the nonfundamental volatility of the securities in their baskets. We exploit exogenous changes in index membership and find that stocks with higher ETF ownership display significantly higher volatility. ETF ownership increases the negative autocorrelation in stock prices. The increase in volatility appears to introduce undiversifiable risk in prices because stocks with high ETF ownership earn a significant risk premium of up to 56 basis points monthly.
Unscheduled News and Market Dynamics
Pages: 2537-2586 | Published: 9/2018 | DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12717 | Cited by: 19
JÉRÔME DUGAST
When unscheduled news arrives, investors react with a stochastic delay yet still may exploit new information. In this context, I study the equilibrium dynamics of limit order markets. Continuous idiosyncratic liquidity shocks result in trades on both sides of the order book. News therefore arrives at random times. Following news, order flows become unbalanced and market depth is consumed, leading to positive covariance between price variability, trading volume, and order book unbalances. Holding the unconditional price variability constant, news frequency has a negative effect on both market depth and the variability‐volume covariance.
Arrested Development: Theory and Evidence of Supply‐Side Speculation in the Housing Market
Pages: 2587-2633 | Published: 10/2018 | DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12719 | Cited by: 49
CHARLES G. NATHANSON, ERIC ZWICK
This paper studies the role of disagreement in amplifying housing cycles. Speculation is easier in the land market than in the housing market due to frictions that make renting less efficient than owner‐occupancy. As a result, undeveloped land facilitates construction and intensifies the speculation that causes booms and busts in house prices. This observation challenges the standard intuition that in cities where construction is easier, house price booms are smaller. It can also explain why the largest house price booms in the United States between 2000 and 2006 occurred in areas with elastic housing supply.
Influencing Control: Jawboning in Risk Arbitrage
Pages: 2635-2675 | Published: 10/2018 | DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12721 | Cited by: 53
WEI JIANG, TAO LI, DANQING MEI
In an “activist risk arbitrage,” a shareholder attempts to improve terms of an announced M&A through public campaigns. Activists target deals with low premiums and those susceptible to managerial conflicts of interest, including going‐private deals and deals in which CEOs receive outsized payments. Activist arbitrageurs are associated with a significant decrease in the probability that targets will be sold to the announced bidders, and an increase in the premium paid, both ex post among surviving deals and ex ante among all deals. Activist arbitrage serves as a governance mechanism in M&A and earns higher returns than passive arbitrage.
Pages: 2677-2717 | Published: 11/2018 | DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12725 | Cited by: 30
SUMIT AGARWAL, GENE AMROMIN, ITZHAK BEN‐DAVID, SERDAR DINC
The U.S. House of Representatives Financial Services Committee considered many important banking reforms in 2009 to 2010. We show that, during this period, foreclosure starts on delinquent mortgages were delayed in the districts of committee members although there was no difference in delinquency rates between committee and noncommittee districts. In these areas, banks delayed the foreclosure starts by 0.5 months (relative to the 12‐month average). The estimated cost of delay to lenders is an order of magnitude greater than the campaign contributions by the political action committees of the largest mortgage servicing banks to the committee members in that period.
Currency Risk Factors in a Recursive Multicountry Economy
Pages: 2719-2756 | Published: 9/2018 | DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12720 | Cited by: 83
RIC COLACITO, MARIANO M. CROCE, FEDERICO GAVAZZONI, ROBERT READY
Focusing on the 10 most traded currencies, we provide empirical evidence regarding a significant heterogeneous exposure to global growth news shocks. We incorporate this empirical fact in a frictionless risk‐sharing model with recursive preferences, multiple countries, and multiple consumption goods whose supply features both global and local short‐ and long‐run shocks. Since news shocks are priced, heterogeneous exposure to long‐lasting global growth shocks results in a relevant reallocation of international resources and currency adjustments. Our unified framework replicates the properties of the HML‐FX and HML‐NFA carry‐trade strategies studied by Lustig, Roussanov, and Verdelhan and Della Corte, Riddiough, and Sarno.
Collateral Constraints and the Law of One Price: An Experiment
Pages: 2757-2786 | Published: 11/2018 | DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12722 | Cited by: 11
MARCO CIPRIANI, ANA FOSTEL, DANIEL HOUSER
We test the asset pricing implications of collateralized borrowing (that is, of using assets as collateral to borrow money) in the laboratory. To this purpose, we develop a general equilibrium model with collateral constraints amenable to laboratory implementation and gather experimental data. In the laboratory, assets that can be leveraged fetch higher prices than assets that cannot, even though assets' payoffs are identical in all states of the world. Collateral value, therefore, creates deviations from the Law of One Price. The spread between collateralizeable and noncollateralizeable assets is significant and quantitatively close to theoretical predictions.
The Impact of Bank Credit on Labor Reallocation and Aggregate Industry Productivity
Pages: 2787-2836 | Published: 10/2018 | DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12726 | Cited by: 120
JOHN (JIANQIU) BAI, DANIEL CARVALHO, GORDON M. PHILLIPS
Pages: 2837-2869 | Published: 10/2018 | DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12724 | Cited by: 82
CAMELIA M. KUHNEN, BRIAN T. MELZER
We investigate a novel determinant of financial distress, namely, individuals' self‐efficacy, or belief that their actions can influence the future. Individuals with high self‐efficacy are more likely to take precautions that mitigate adverse financial shocks. They are subsequently less likely to default on their debt and bill payments, especially after experiencing negative shocks such as job loss or illness. Thus, noncognitive abilities are an important determinant of financial fragility and subjective expectations are an important factor in household financial decisions.
Sensation Seeking and Hedge Funds
Pages: 2871-2914 | Published: 11/2018 | DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12723 | Cited by: 64
STEPHEN BROWN, YAN LU, SUGATA RAY, MELVYN TEO
We show that, motivated by sensation seeking, hedge fund managers who own powerful sports cars take on more investment risk but do not deliver higher returns, resulting in lower Sharpe ratios, information ratios, and alphas. Moreover, sensation‐seeking managers trade more frequently, actively, and unconventionally, and prefer lottery‐like stocks. We show further that some investors are themselves susceptible to sensation seeking and that sensation‐seeking investors fuel the demand for sensation‐seeking managers. While investors perceive sensation seekers to be less competent, they do not fully appreciate the superior investment skills of sensation‐avoiding fund managers.
AFA 2019 ATLANTA MEETINGS SEVENTY‐NINTH ANNUAL MEETING AMERICAN FINANCE ASSOCIATION Atlanta, Georgia
Pages: 2918-2966 | Published: 11/2018 | DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12576 | Cited by: 3
Participant Schedule Report Participants in the AFA 2019 Atlanta Meetings January 4–6, 2019
Pages: 2967-3024 | Published: 11/2018 | DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12741 | Cited by: 0
Pages: 3025-3025 | Published: 11/2018 | DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12742 | Cited by: 4
Kenneth Singleton