View All Issues

Volume 61: Issue 2 (April 2006)


Bank Mergers and Crime: The Real and Social Effects of Credit Market Competition

Pages: 495-538  |  Published: 3/2006  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2006.00847.x  |  Cited by: 162

MARK J. GARMAISE, TOBIAS J. MOSKOWITZ

Using a unique sample of commercial loans and mergers between large banks, we provide micro‐level (within‐county) evidence linking credit conditions to economic development and find a spillover effect on crime. Neighborhoods that experience more bank mergers are subject to higher interest rates, diminished local construction, lower prices, an influx of poorer households, and higher property crime in subsequent years. The elasticity of property crime with respect to merger‐induced banking concentration is 0.18. We show that these results are not likely due to reverse causation, and confirm the central findings using state branching deregulation to instrument for bank competition.


A Consumption‐Based Explanation of Expected Stock Returns

Pages: 539-580  |  Published: 3/2006  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2006.00848.x  |  Cited by: 472

MOTOHIRO YOGO

When utility is nonseparable in nondurable and durable consumption and the elasticity of substitution between the two consumption goods is sufficiently high, marginal utility rises when durable consumption falls. The model explains both the cross‐sectional variation in expected stock returns and the time variation in the equity premium. Small stocks and value stocks deliver relatively low returns during recessions, when durable consumption falls, which explains their high average returns relative to big stocks and growth stocks. Stock returns are unexpectedly low at business cycle troughs, when durable consumption falls sharply, which explains the countercyclical variation in the equity premium.


Do the Fama–French Factors Proxy for Innovations in Predictive Variables?

Pages: 581-612  |  Published: 3/2006  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2006.00849.x  |  Cited by: 486

RALITSA PETKOVA


Risk, Reputation, and IPO Price Support

Pages: 613-653  |  Published: 3/2006  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2006.00850.x  |  Cited by: 71

KATHARINA LEWELLEN

Immediately following an initial public offering, underwriters often repurchase shares of poorly performing offerings in an apparent attempt to stabilize the price. Using proprietary Nasdaq data, I study the price effects and determinants of price support. Some of the key findings are (1) Stabilization is substantial, inducing price rigidity at and below the offer price; (2) I find no evidence that stocks with larger information asymmetries are stabilized more strongly; (3) Larger underwriters stabilize more, perhaps to protect their reputations with investors; and (4) Investment banks with retail brokerage operations stabilize much more than other banks, inconsistent with the view that stabilization benefits primarily institutional investors.


Does Weak Governance Cause Weak Stock Returns? An Examination of Firm Operating Performance and Investors' Expectations

Pages: 655-687  |  Published: 3/2006  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2006.00851.x  |  Cited by: 631

JOHN E. CORE, WAYNE R. GUAY, TJOMME O. RUSTICUS

We investigate Gompers, Ishii, and Metrick's (2003) finding that firms with weak shareholder rights exhibit significant stock market underperformance. If the relation between poor governance and poor returns is causal, we expect that the market is negatively surprised by the poor operating performance of weak governance firms. We find that firms with weak shareholder rights exhibit significant operating underperformance. However, analysts' forecast errors and earnings announcement returns show no evidence that this underperformance surprises the market. Our results are robust to controls for takeover activity. Overall, our results do not support the hypothesis that weak governance causes poor stock returns.


Are Busy Boards Effective Monitors?

Pages: 689-724  |  Published: 3/2006  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2006.00852.x  |  Cited by: 1295

ELIEZER M. FICH, ANIL SHIVDASANI

Firms with busy boards, those in which a majority of outside directors hold three or more directorships, are associated with weak corporate governance. These firms exhibit lower market‐to‐book ratios, weaker profitability, and lower sensitivity of CEO turnover to firm performance. Independent but busy boards display CEO turnover‐performance sensitivities indistinguishable from those of inside‐dominated boards. Departures of busy outside directors generate positive abnormal returns (ARs). When directors become busy as a result of acquiring an additional directorship, other companies in which they hold board seats experience negative ARs. Busy outside directors are more likely to depart boards following poor performance.


Does Investor Misvaluation Drive the Takeover Market?

Pages: 725-762  |  Published: 3/2006  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2006.00853.x  |  Cited by: 663

MING DONG, DAVID HIRSHLEIFER, SCOTT RICHARDSON, SIEW HONG TEOH

This paper uses pre‐offer market valuations to evaluate the misvaluation and Q theories of takeovers. Bidder and target valuations (price‐to‐book, or price‐to‐residual‐income‐model‐value) are related to means of payment, mode of acquisition, premia, target hostility, offer success, and bidder and target announcement‐period returns. The evidence is broadly consistent with both hypotheses. The evidence for the Q hypothesis is stronger in the pre‐1990 period than in the 1990–2000 period, whereas the evidence for the misvaluation hypothesis is stronger in the 1990–2000 period than in the pre‐1990 period.


Offering versus Choice in 401(k) Plans: Equity Exposure and Number of Funds

Pages: 763-801  |  Published: 3/2006  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2006.00854.x  |  Cited by: 245

GUR HUBERMAN, WEI JIANG

Records of over half a million participants in more than 600 401(k) plans indicate that participants tend to allocate their contributions evenly across the funds they use, with the tendency weakening with the number of funds used. The number of funds used, typically between three and four, is not sensitive to the number of funds offered by the plans, which ranges from 4 to 59. A participant's propensity to allocate contributions to equity funds is not very sensitive to the fraction of equity funds among offered funds. The paper also comments on limitations on inferences from experiments and aggregate‐level data analysis.


The Entrepreneur's Choice between Private and Public Ownership

Pages: 803-836  |  Published: 3/2006  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2006.00855.x  |  Cited by: 188

ARNOUD W. A. BOOT, RADHAKRISHNAN GOPALAN, ANJAN V. THAKOR

We analyze an entrepreneur/manager's choice between private and public ownership. The manager needs decision‐making autonomy to optimally manage the firm and thus trades off an endogenized control preference against the higher cost of capital accompanying greater managerial autonomy. Investors need liquid ownership stakes. Public capital markets provide liquidity, but stipulate corporate governance that imposes generic exogenous controls, so the manager may not attain the desired trade‐off between autonomy and the cost of capital. In contrast, private ownership provides the desired trade‐off through precisely calibrated contracting, but creates illiquid ownership. Exploring this tension generates new predictions.


Market Valuation of Tax‐Timing Options: Evidence from Capital Gains Distributions

Pages: 837-865  |  Published: 3/2006  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2006.00856.x  |  Cited by: 42

J. B. CHAY, DOSOUNG CHOI, JEFFREY PONTIFF

We examine a distribution that is taxed as a capital gain rather than as a dividend. Since the distribution induces a realized capital gain while the price change is an unrealized gain, ex‐day return behavior provides evidence of the value of tax‐timing capital gains. We show that investors are compensated 7¢ in unrealized gains for each dollar of realized capital gains, that is, $1 of realized capital gains is equivalent to 93¢ of unrealized gains. An investor with a tax rate on realized gains of 15% has an effective tax rate on unrealized capital gains of 8.6%.


Banks' Advantage in Hedging Liquidity Risk: Theory and Evidence from the Commercial Paper Market

Pages: 867-892  |  Published: 3/2006  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2006.00857.x  |  Cited by: 377

EVAN GATEV, PHILIP E. STRAHAN

Banks have a unique ability to hedge against market‐wide liquidity shocks. Deposit inflows provide funding for loan demand shocks that follow declines in market liquidity. Consequently, banks can insure firms against systematic declines in liquidity at lower cost than other institutions. We provide evidence that when liquidity dries up and commercial paper spreads widen, banks experience funding inflows. These flows allow banks to meet loan demand from borrowers drawing funds from commercial paper backup lines without running down their holdings of liquid assets. We also provide evidence that implicit government support for banks during crises explains these funding flows.


Firm Value and Hedging: Evidence from U.S. Oil and Gas Producers

Pages: 893-919  |  Published: 3/2006  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2006.00858.x  |  Cited by: 453

YANBO JIN, PHILIPPE JORION

This paper studies the hedging activities of 119 U.S. oil and gas producers from 1998 to 2001 and evaluates their effect on firm value. Theories of hedging based on market imperfections imply that hedging should increase the firm's market value (MV). To test this hypothesis, we collect detailed information on the extent of hedging and on the valuation of oil and gas reserves. We verify that hedging reduces the firm's stock price sensitivity to oil and gas prices. Contrary to previous studies, however, we find that hedging does not seem to affect MVs for this industry.


Pension Plan Funding and Stock Market Efficiency

Pages: 921-956  |  Published: 3/2006  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2006.00859.x  |  Cited by: 176

FRANCESCO FRANZONI, JOSÉ M. MARÍN

The paper argues that the market significantly overvalues firms with severely underfunded pension plans. These companies earn lower stock returns than firms with healthier pension plans for at least 5 years after the first emergence of the underfunding. The low returns are not explained by risk, price momentum, earnings momentum, or accruals. Further, the evidence suggests that investors do not anticipate the impact of the pension liability on future earnings, and they are surprised when the negative implications of underfunding ultimately materialize. Finally, underfunded firms have poor operating performance, and they earn low returns, although they are value companies.


How Do Crises Spread? Evidence from Accessible and Inaccessible Stock Indices

Pages: 957-1003  |  Published: 3/2006  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2006.00860.x  |  Cited by: 323

BRIAN H. BOYER, TOMOMI KUMAGAI, KATHY YUAN

We provide empirical evidence that stock market crises are spread globally through asset holdings of international investors. By separating emerging market stocks into two categories, namely, those that are eligible for purchase by foreigners (accessible) and those that are not (inaccessible), we estimate and compare the degree to which accessible and inaccessible stock index returns co‐move with crisis country index returns. Our results show greater co‐movement during high volatility periods, especially for accessible stock index returns, suggesting that crises spread through the asset holdings of international investors rather than through changes in fundamentals.


MISCELLANEA

Pages: 1005-1006  |  Published: 3/2006  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2006.00861.x  |  Cited by: 3