View All Issues

Volume 62: Issue 5 (October 2007)


Supply and Demand Shifts in the Shorting Market

Pages: 2061-2096  |  Published: 9/2007  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2007.01269.x  |  Cited by: 324

LAUREN COHEN, KARL B. DIETHER, CHRISTOPHER J. MALLOY

Using proprietary data on stock loan fees and quantities from a large institutional investor, we examine the link between the shorting market and stock prices. Employing a unique identification strategy, we isolate shifts in the supply and demand for shorting. We find that shorting demand is an important predictor of future stock returns: An increase in shorting demand leads to negative abnormal returns of 2.98% in the following month. Second, we show that our results are stronger in environments with less public information flow, suggesting that the shorting market is an important mechanism for private information revelation.


Short‐Sales Constraints and Price Discovery: Evidence from the Hong Kong Market

Pages: 2097-2121  |  Published: 9/2007  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2007.01270.x  |  Cited by: 344

ERIC C. CHANG, JOSEPH W. CHENG, YINGHUI YU

Short‐sales practices in the Hong Kong stock market are unique in that only stocks on a list of designated securities can be sold short. By analyzing the price effects following the addition of individual stocks to the list, we find that short‐sales constraints tend to cause stock overvaluation and that the overvaluation effect is more dramatic for individual stocks for which wider dispersion of investor opinions exists. These findings are consistent with Miller's (1977) intuition and other optimism models. We also document higher volatility and less positive skewness of individual stock returns when short sales are allowed.


Portfolio Choice over the Life‐Cycle when the Stock and Labor Markets Are Cointegrated

Pages: 2123-2167  |  Published: 9/2007  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2007.01271.x  |  Cited by: 317

LUCA BENZONI, PIERRE COLLIN‐DUFRESNE, ROBERT S. GOLDSTEIN

We study portfolio choice when labor income and dividends are cointegrated. Economically plausible calibrations suggest young investors should take substantial short positions in the stock market. Because of cointegration the young agent's human capital effectively becomes “stock‐like.” However, for older agents with shorter times‐to‐retirement, cointegration does not have sufficient time to act, and thus their human capital becomes more “bond‐like.” Together, these effects create hump‐shaped life‐cycle portfolio holdings, consistent with empirical observation. These results hold even when asset return predictability is accounted for.


Multimarket Trading and Liquidity: Theory and Evidence

Pages: 2169-2200  |  Published: 9/2007  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2007.01272.x  |  Cited by: 120

SHMUEL BARUCH, G. ANDREW KAROLYI, MICHAEL L. LEMMON

We develop a new model of multimarket trading to explain the differences in the foreign share of trading volume of internationally cross‐listed stocks. The model predicts that the trading volume of a cross‐listed stock is proportionally higher on the exchange in which the cross‐listed asset returns have greater correlation with returns of other assets traded on that market. We find robust empirical support for this prediction using stock return and volume data on 251 non‐U.S. stocks cross‐listed on major U.S. exchanges.


Liquidity and the Law of One Price: The Case of the Futures‐Cash Basis

Pages: 2201-2234  |  Published: 9/2007  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2007.01273.x  |  Cited by: 146

RICHARD ROLL, EDUARDO SCHWARTZ, AVANIDHAR SUBRAHMANYAM

Deviations from no‐arbitrage relations should be related to market liquidity, because liquidity facilitates arbitrage. At the same time, a wide futures‐cash basis may trigger arbitrage trades and, in turn, affect liquidity. We test these ideas by studying the dynamic relation between stock market liquidity and the index futures basis. There is evidence of two‐way Granger causality between the short‐term absolute basis and liquidity, and liquidity Granger‐causes longer‐term absolute bases. Shocks to the absolute basis predict future stock market liquidity. The evidence suggests that liquidity enhances the efficiency of the futures‐cash pricing system.


Episodic Liquidity Crises: Cooperative and Predatory Trading

Pages: 2235-2274  |  Published: 9/2007  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2007.01274.x  |  Cited by: 196

BRUCE IAN CARLIN, MIGUEL SOUSA LOBO, S. VISWANATHAN

We describe how episodic illiquidity arises from a breakdown in cooperation between market participants. We first solve a one‐period trading game in continuous‐time, using an asset pricing equation that accounts for the price impact of trading. Then, in a multi‐period framework, we describe an equilibrium in which traders cooperate most of the time through repeated interaction, providing apparent liquidity to one another. Cooperation breaks down when the stakes are high, leading to predatory trading and episodic illiquidity. Equilibrium strategies that involve cooperation across markets lead to less frequent episodic illiquidity, but cause contagion when cooperation breaks down.


Liquidity Coinsurance, Moral Hazard, and Financial Contagion

Pages: 2275-2302  |  Published: 9/2007  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2007.01275.x  |  Cited by: 134

SANDRO BRUSCO, FABIO CASTIGLIONESI

We study the propagation of financial crises among regions in which banks are protected by limited liability and may take excessive risk. The regions are affected by negatively correlated liquidity shocks, so liquidity coinsurance is Pareto improving. The moral hazard problem can be solved if banks are sufficiently capitalized. Under autarky a limited amount of capital is sufficient to prevent risk‐taking, but when financial markets are open capital becomes insufficient. Thus, bankruptcy occurs with positive probability and the crisis spreads to other regions via financial linkages. Opening financial markets is nevertheless Pareto improving; consumers benefit from liquidity coinsurance, although they pay the cost of excessive risk‐taking.


Liquidity or Credit Risk? The Determinants of Very Short‐Term Corporate Yield Spreads

Pages: 2303-2328  |  Published: 9/2007  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2007.01276.x  |  Cited by: 115

DAN COVITZ, CHRIS DOWNING

Employing a comprehensive database on transactions of commercial paper issued by domestic U.S. nonfinancial corporations, we study the determinants of very short‐term corporate yield spreads. We find that liquidity plays a role in the determination of spreads but, somewhat surprisingly, credit quality is the more important determinant of spreads, even at horizons of less than 1 month. These results are robust across a variety of proxies for liquidity and credit risk, and have important implications for the literature on the modeling of corporate bond prices.


Liquidity Premia and Transaction Costs

Pages: 2329-2366  |  Published: 9/2007  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2007.01277.x  |  Cited by: 132

BONG‐GYU JANG, HYENG KEUN KOO, HONG LIU, MARK LOEWENSTEIN

Standard literature concludes that transaction costs only have a second‐order effect on liquidity premia. We show that this conclusion depends crucially on the assumption of a constant investment opportunity set. In a regime‐switching model in which the investment opportunity set varies over time, we explicitly characterize the optimal consumption and investment strategy. In contrast to the standard literature, we find that transaction costs can have a first‐order effect on liquidity premia. However, with reasonably calibrated parameters, the presence of transaction costs still cannot fully explain the equity premium puzzle.


Analyst Disagreement, Mispricing, and Liquidity*

Pages: 2367-2403  |  Published: 9/2007  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2007.01278.x  |  Cited by: 243

RONNIE SADKA, ANNA SCHERBINA

This paper documents a close link between mispricing and liquidity by investigating stocks with high analyst disagreement. Previous research finds that these stocks tend to be overpriced, but that prices correct downwards as uncertainty about earnings is resolved. Our analysis suggests that one reason mispricing has persisted through the years is that analyst disagreement coincides with high trading costs. We also show that in the cross‐section, the less liquid stocks tend to be more severely overpriced. Additionally, increases in aggregate market liquidity accelerate the convergence of prices to fundamentals. As a result, returns of the initially overpriced stocks are negatively correlated with the time series of innovations in aggregate market liquidity.


Taking a View: Corporate Speculation, Governance, and Compensation

Pages: 2405-2443  |  Published: 9/2007  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2007.01279.x  |  Cited by: 159

CHRISTOPHER C. GÉCZY, BERNADETTE A. MINTON, CATHERINE M. SCHRAND

Using responses to a well‐known confidential survey, we study corporations' use of derivatives to “take a view” on interest rate and currency movements. Characteristics of speculators suggest that perceived information and cost advantages lead them to take positions actively; that is, they do not speculate to increase risk by “betting the ranch.” Speculating firms encourage managers to speculate through incentive‐aligning compensation arrangements and bonding contracts, and they use derivatives‐specific internal controls to manage potential abuse. Finally, we examine whether investors reading public corporate disclosures are able to identify firms that indicate speculating in the confidential survey; they are not.


Financial Constraints, Competition, and Hedging in Industry Equilibrium

Pages: 2445-2473  |  Published: 9/2007  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2007.01280.x  |  Cited by: 104

TIM ADAM, SUDIPTO DASGUPTA, SHERIDAN TITMAN

We analyze the hedging decisions of firms, within an equilibrium setting that allows us to examine how a firm's hedging choice depends on the hedging choices of its competitors. Within this equilibrium some firms hedge while others do not, even though all firms are ex ante identical. The fraction of firms that hedge depends on industry characteristics, such as the number of firms in the industry, the elasticity of demand, and the convexity of production costs. Consistent with prior empirical findings, the model predicts that there is more heterogeneity in the decision to hedge in the most competitive industries.


Exchange Rates and Cash Flows in Differentiated Product Industries: A Simulation Approach

Pages: 2475-2502  |  Published: 9/2007  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2007.01281.x  |  Cited by: 7

RICHARD FRIBERG, MATTIAS GANSLANDT

How do exchange rate changes impact firms' cash flows? We extend a simulation method developed in industrial organization to answer this question. We use prices, quantities, and product characteristics for differentiated products, coupled with a discrete choice framework and an assumption of price competition, to estimate marginal costs for all producers. Using a Monte Carlo approach we generate counterfactual prices and profits for different levels of exchange rates. We illustrate the method using the market for bottled water. Our results stress that even in a relatively simple market such as this one, different brands face very different exchange rate risks.


Momentum and Credit Rating

Pages: 2503-2520  |  Published: 9/2007  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2007.01282.x  |  Cited by: 288

DORON AVRAMOV, TARUN CHORDIA, GERGANA JOSTOVA, ALEXANDER PHILIPOV

This paper establishes a robust link between momentum and credit rating. Momentum profitability is large and significant among low‐grade firms, but it is nonexistent among high‐grade firms. The momentum payoffs documented in the literature are generated by low‐grade firms that account for less than 4% of the overall market capitalization of rated firms. The momentum payoff differential across credit rating groups is unexplained by firm size, firm age, analyst forecast dispersion, leverage, return volatility, and cash flow volatility.


Price Convexity and Skewness

Pages: 2521-2552  |  Published: 9/2007  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2007.01283.x  |  Cited by: 95

JIANGUO XU

This paper develops a model in which investors who are prohibited from short selling agree to disagree on the precision of a publicly observed signal. The model implies that the equilibrium price is a convex function of the public signal. The model predicts that (1) the stock price reacts more to good news than to bad news; (2) the skewness of stock returns is positively correlated with contemporaneous returns, but negatively correlated with lagged returns; (3) short sale constraints increase rather than decrease skewness; and (4) disagreement about information precision increases skewness. Empirical tests conducted find supportive evidence for all these predictions.


MISCELLANEA

Pages: 2553-2554  |  Published: 9/2007  |  DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2007.01284.x  |  Cited by: 0