The Journal of Finance

The Journal of Finance publishes leading research across all the major fields of finance. It is one of the most widely cited journals in academic finance, and in all of economics. Each of the six issues per year reaches over 8,000 academics, finance professionals, libraries, and government and financial institutions around the world. The journal is the official publication of The American Finance Association, the premier academic organization devoted to the study and promotion of knowledge about financial economics.

AFA members can log in to view full-text articles below.

View past issues


Search the Journal of Finance:






Search results: 160. Page: 2
Go to: <<Previous 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Next>>

Exodus from Sovereign Risk: Global Asset and Information Networks in the Pricing of Corporate Credit Risk

Published: 04/19/2016   |   DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12412

JONGSUB LEE, ANDY NARANJO, STACE SIRMANS

Using five‐year credit default swap (CDS) spreads on 2,364 companies in 54 countries from 2004 to 2011, we find that firms exposed to stronger property rights through their foreign asset positions (institutional channel) and firms cross‐listed on exchanges with stricter disclosure requirements (informational channel) reduce their CDS spreads by 40 bps for a one‐standard‐deviation increase in their exposure to the two channels. These channels capture effects beyond those associated with firm‐ and country‐level fundamentals. Overall, we find that firm‐level global asset and information connections are important mechanisms to delink firms from their sovereign and country risks.


Time Variation of Ex‐Dividend Day Stock Returns and Corporate Dividend Capture: A Reexamination

Published: 12/17/2002   |   DOI: 10.1111/0022-1082.00290

Andy Naranjo, M. Nimalendran, Mike Ryngaert

This paper documents some empirical facts about ex‐day abnormal returns to high dividend yield stocks that are potentially subject to corporate dividend capture. We find that average abnormal ex‐dividend day returns are uniformly negative in each year after the introduction of negotiated commission rates and that time variation in ex‐day returns during the negotiated commission rates era is consistent with corporate tax‐based dividend capture. Ex‐day returns are more negative when the tax advantage to corporate dividend capture is greatest and more positive when increases in transaction costs and risk reduce incentives to engage in corporate tax‐based dividend capture.


Individualism and Momentum around the World

Published: 01/13/2010   |   DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2009.01532.x

ANDY C.W. CHUI, SHERIDAN TITMAN, K.C. JOHN WEI

This paper examines how cultural differences influence the returns of momentum strategies. Cross‐country cultural differences are measured with an individualism index developed by Hofstede (2001), which is related to overconfidence and self‐attribution bias. We find that individualism is positively associated with trading volume and volatility, as well as to the magnitude of momentum profits. Momentum profits are also positively related to analyst forecast dispersion, transaction costs, and the familiarity of the market to foreigners, and negatively related to firm size and volatility. However, the addition of these and other variables does not dampen the relation between individualism and momentum profits.


DISCUSSION

Published: 07/01/1984   |   DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1984.tb03685.x

ANDREW H. CHEN


Trade Generation, Reputation, and Sell‐Side Analysts

Published: 03/02/2005   |   DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2005.00743.x

ANDREW R. JACKSON

This paper examines the trade‐generation and reputation‐building incentives facing sell‐side analysts. Using a unique data set I demonstrate that optimistic analysts generate more trade for their brokerage firms, as do high reputation analysts. I also find that accurate analysts generate higher reputations. The analyst therefore faces a conflict between telling the truth to build her reputation versus misleading investors via optimistic forecasts to generate short‐term increases in trading commissions. In equilibrium I show forecast optimism can exist, even when investment‐banking affiliations are removed. The conclusions may have important policy implications given recent changes in the institutional structure of the brokerage industry.


THE FIRM'S OPTIMAL FINANCIAL DECISIONS: AN INTEGRATION OF CORPORATE FINANCIAL THEORY UNDER CERTAINTY*

Published: 12/01/1974   |   DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1974.tb03148.x

Andrew J. Senchack


Proxy Advisory Firms: The Economics of Selling Information to Voters

Published: 04/17/2019   |   DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12779

ANDREY MALENKO, NADYA MALENKO

We analyze how proxy advisors, which sell voting recommendations to shareholders, affect corporate decision‐making. If the quality of the advisor's information is low, there is overreliance on its recommendations and insufficient private information production. In contrast, if the advisor's information is precise, it may be underused because the advisor rations its recommendations to maximize profits. Overall, the advisor's presence leads to more informative voting only if its information is sufficiently precise. We evaluate several proposals on regulating proxy advisors and show that some suggested policies, such as reducing proxy advisors' market power or decreasing litigation pressure, can have negative effects.


Risk‐Sharing and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Published: 05/11/2022   |   DOI: 10.1111/jofi.13139

ANDRÉS SCHNEIDER

I propose a general equilibrium model with heterogeneous investors to explain the key properties of the U.S. real and nominal term structure of interest rates. I find that differences in investors' elasticities of intertemporal substitution are critical in accounting for the dynamics of nominal and real yields. The nominal term structure is driven primarily by real shocks so that it can be upward sloping regardless of the correlation between nominal and real shocks.


DISCUSSION

Published: 05/01/1973   |   DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1973.tb01789.x

Andreas G. Papandreou


Strategic and Financial Bidders in Takeover Auctions

Published: 08/06/2014   |   DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12194

ALEXANDER  S. GORBENKO, ANDREY MALENKO

Using data on auctions of companies, we estimate valuations (maximum willingness to pay) of strategic and financial bidders from their bids. We find that a typical target is valued higher by strategic bidders. However, 22.4% of targets in our sample are valued higher by financial bidders. These are mature, poorly performing companies. We also find that (i) valuations of different strategic bidders are more dispersed and (ii) valuations of financial bidders are correlated with aggregate economic conditions. Our results suggest that different targets appeal to different types of bidders, rather than that strategic bidders always value targets more because of synergies.


Which Investors Fear Expropriation? Evidence from Investors' Portfolio Choices

Published: 05/16/2006   |   DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2006.00879.x

MARIASSUNTA GIANNETTI, ANDREI SIMONOV

Using a data set that provides unprecedented detail on investors' stockholdings, we analyze whether investors take the quality of corporate governance into account when selecting stocks. We find that all categories of investors (domestic and foreign, institutional and small individual) who generally enjoy only security benefits are reluctant to invest in companies with weak corporate governance. In contrast, individuals connected with company insiders are more likely to invest in weak corporate governance companies. These findings suggest that it is important to distinguish between investors who enjoy private benefits or access private information, and investors who enjoy only security benefits.


Theories of Corporate Debt Policy: A Synthesis

Published: 05/01/1979   |   DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1979.tb02098.x

ANDREW H. CHEN, E. HAN KIM


Corporate Fraud and Business Conditions: Evidence from IPOs

Published: 11/09/2010   |   DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2010.01615.x

TRACY YUE WANG, ANDREW WINTON, XIAOYUN YU

We examine how a firm's incentive to commit fraud when going public varies with investor beliefs about industry business conditions. Fraud propensity increases with the level of investor beliefs about industry prospects but decreases when beliefs are extremely high. We find that two mechanisms are at work: monitoring by investors and short‐term executive compensation, both of which vary with investor beliefs about industry prospects. We also find that monitoring incentives of investors and underwriters differ. Our results are consistent with models of investor beliefs and corporate fraud, and suggest that regulators and auditors should be vigilant for fraud during booms.


On the High‐Frequency Dynamics of Hedge Fund Risk Exposures

Published: 11/26/2012   |   DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12008

ANDREW J. PATTON, TARUN RAMADORAI

We propose a new method to model hedge fund risk exposures using relatively high‐frequency conditioning variables. In a large sample of funds, we find substantial evidence that hedge fund risk exposures vary across and within months, and that capturing within‐month variation is more important for hedge funds than for mutual funds. We consider different within‐month functional forms, and uncover patterns such as day‐of‐the‐month variation in risk exposures. We also find that changes in portfolio allocations, rather than in the risk exposures of the underlying assets, are the main drivers of hedge funds' risk exposure variation.


Auctions with Endogenous Initiation

Published: 11/02/2023   |   DOI: 10.1111/jofi.13288

ALEXANDER S. GORBENKO, ANDREY MALENKO

We study initiation of takeover auctions by potential buyers and the seller. A bidder's indication of interest reveals that she is optimistic about the target. If bidders' values have a substantial common component, as in takeover battles between financial bidders, this effect disincentivizes bidders from indicating interest, and auctions are seller‐initiated. Conversely, in private‐value auctions, such as battles between strategic bidders, equilibria can feature both seller‐ and bidder‐initiated auctions, with the likelihood of the latter decreasing in commonality of values and the probability of a forced sale by the seller. We also relate initiation to bids and auction outcomes.


Ownership Structure, Speculation, and Shareholder Intervention

Published: 12/17/2002   |   DOI: 10.1111/0022-1082.45483

Charles Kahn, Andrew Winton

An institution holding shares in a firm can use information about the firm both for trading (“speculation”) and for deciding whether to intervene to improve firm performance. Intervention increases the value of the institution's existing shareholdings, but intervention only increases the institution's trading profits if it enhances the precision of the institution's information relative to that of uninformed traders. Thus, the ability to speculate can increase or decrease institutional intervention. We examine key factors that affect the intervention decision, the usefulness of “short‐swing” provisions and restricted shares in encouraging institutional intervention, and implications for ownership structure across different firms.


Index Options: The Early Evidence

Published: 07/01/1985   |   DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1985.tb04998.x

JEREMY EVNINE, ANDREW RUDD

Index options became the most important traded contracts during their first year of existence. Two contracts, namely those on the S&P100 and the Major Markets Index, have a trading volume which typically surpasses the trading volume in all individual stock option contracts. In this paper, we examine the pricing of the options on the S&P100 and the Major Markets Index. Using intra‐day prices, we find the options frequently violate the arbitrage boundary, put/call parity, and are substantially mispriced relative to theoretical values. Our results suggest that tests of option pricing models may be more difficult than previously realized due to nonsynchronous prices, even using “real‐time” data from the exchanges.


Moral Hazard and Optimal Subsidiary Structure for Financial Institutions

Published: 11/27/2005   |   DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2004.00708.x

CHARLES KAHN, ANDREW WINTON

Banks and related financial institutions often have two separate subsidiaries that make loans of similar type but differing risk, for example, a bank and a finance company, or a “good bank/bad bank” structure. Such “bipartite” structures may prevent risk shifting, in which banks misuse their flexibility in choosing and monitoring loans to exploit their debt holders. By “insulating” safer loans from riskier loans, a bipartite structure reduces risk‐shifting incentives in the safer subsidiary. Bipartite structures are more likely to dominate unitary structures as the downside from riskier loans is higher or as expected profits from the efficient loan mix are lower.


Labor Mobility: Implications for Asset Pricing

Published: 01/16/2014   |   DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12141

ANDRÉS DONANGELO

Labor mobility is the flexibility of workers to walk away from an industry in response to better opportunities. I develop a model in which labor flows make bad times worse for shareholders who are left with capital that is less productive. The model shows that firms face greater operating leverage by providing flexibility to mobile workers. I construct an empirical measure of labor mobility consistent with the model and document an economically significant cross‐sectional relation between mobility, operating leverage, and stock returns. I find that firms in mobile industries earn returns over 5% higher than those in less mobile industries.


Family Firms

Published: 09/11/2003   |   DOI: 10.1111/1540-6261.00601

Mike Burkart, Fausto Panunzi, Andrei Shleifer

We present a model of succession in a firm owned and managed by its founder. The founder decides between hiring a professional manager or leaving management to his heir, as well as on what fraction of the company to float on the stock exchange. We assume that a professional is a better manager than the heir, and describe how the founder's decision is shaped by the legal environment. This theory of separation of ownership from management includes the Anglo‐Saxon and the Continental European patterns of corporate governance as special cases, and generates additional empirical predictions consistent with cross‐country evidence.



Go to: <<Previous 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Next>>